Search over 40,000 articles from the original, classic Encyclopedia Britannica, 11th Edition.
See also:NATIONAL See also:DEBT . Details as to the See also:recent figures of the national debts of individual countries are given under the heading of each See also:country, and the reader is also referred to the See also:article See also:FINANCE. Here the subject is considered in its technical aspects—including the See also:special See also:character of the institution, the different classes of debt, the various methods of raising loans, See also:interest, funding systems, See also:comparative See also:statistics of national debts and other points. National debt is so universal that it has been described as the first See also:stage of a nation towards See also:civilization. A nation, so far as its finances are concerned, may be regarded as a corporate See also:body or even as an individual. Like the one or the other it may See also:borrow See also:money at rates of interest, and with securities, See also:general or special, proportionate to its resources, See also:credit and stability. But, while in this respect there are certain points of See also:analogy between a See also:state and an individual, there are important points of difference so far as the question of debt is concerned. A state, for example, may be regarded as imperishable, and its debt as a of See also:England were wont to exact from the See also:Jews were really of the character of forced loans, though the method has never been used in England in See also:modern times so extensively as on the See also:continent. There the sum sought to be obtained in this way has never been anything like realized. In 1793, for example, a See also:loan of this class was imposed in See also:France, on the basis of income; and of the milliard (francs) which it was sought to raise only See also:loo millions were realized. In See also:Austria and See also:Spain, also, recourse has been had at various times to forced loans, but invariably with unsatisfactory results. Other methods of a more or less compulsory character have been and are made use of in various states for obtaining money, which, as they involve the See also:payment of interest, may be regarded as of the nature of loans; but the debt incurred by such methods is comparatively insignificant, and some of the methods adopted are peculiarly irritating and mischievous. On the other See also:hand, it has occasionally been attempted to raise voluntary loans by appeals to a nation's patriotism; the method has been confined almost exclusively to France. After the revolutions of 183o and 1848 appeals were
permanent institution which it is not See also:bound to liquidate at any definite See also:period, the interest, unless specially stipulated, being thus of the nature of transferable permanent annuities. While an individual who borrows engages to pay interest to the lender personally, and to reimburse the entire debt by a certain date, a state may have an entirely different set of creditors every six months, and may make no stipulation whatever with regard to the See also:principal. A state, moreover, is the See also:sole See also:judge of its own solvency, and is not only at See also:liberty either to repudiate its debts or See also:compound with its creditors, but even when perfectly solvent may materially alter the conditions on which it originally borrowed. These distinctions explain many of the peculiarities of national debts as contrasted with those of individuals—though a nation, like an individual, may by reckless See also:bad faith utterly destroy its credit and exhaust its borrowing See also:powers.
A well-organized state ought to have within itself the means of See also:meeting all its See also:ordinary expenses; where this is not the See also:case, either through insufficiency of resources or maladministration, and where borrowing is resorted to for what may be regarded as current expenses, a state imperils, not only its credit, but, when any crisis occurs, its very existence; in See also:illustration of this we need only refer to the cases of See also:Turkey in See also:Europe and some of the states of Central and See also:South See also:America. Even for meeting emergencies it is not always inevitable that a state should incur debt; its ordinary resources, from See also:taxation or from state See also:property, may so exceed its ordinary expenses as to enable it to accumulate a fund for extraordinary contingencies. This, it would seem, was a method commonly adopted in See also:ancient states. The Athenians, for example, amassed ro,000 talents in the See also:interval between the See also:Persian and the Peloponnesian See also:wars, and the Lacedaemonians are said to have done the same. At See also:Susa and See also:Ecbatana See also: We find that the method of accumulating reserves prevailed among some of the early See also:French See also:kings, even down to the See also:time of See also: The loans which the kings thus made to the patriotism of French capitalists to buy 5% See also:direct from the See also:government at See also:par, at a time when the French 5% were selling at 8o; but the results were quite insignificant. In See also:short, the only economically See also:sound method of meeting expenses which the ordinary resources of a state cannot meet is by borrowing in the open See also:market on the most advantageous terms obtainable. On this normal method of borrowing, loans are divided into different categories, though there are really only two See also:main classes, which may be designated perpetual and terminable. Borrowing in quasi-See also:perpetuity has hitherto been. the mode adopted by most states in the creation of the bulk of their debt. Not that any state ever borrows with the avowed intention of never paying off debts; but either no definite period for reimbursement is fixed, or the limit has been so extended as to be practically perpetual, or in actual practice the debt has been got rid of by the creation of another of equal amount under similar or slightly differing conditions as to interest. Of course a state is not bound to retain any See also:part of its debt as a perpetual See also:burden; it is at liberty to liquidate whenever it suits its convenience. This quasi-perpetuity of debt in the case of a state in a sound financial See also:condition involves no hardship upon its creditors, who may at any moment realize their invested See also:capital by selling their titles as creditors in the open money market, it may be at the See also:price they paid, or it may be a little below or a little above it, according to the state of the market at the time. Loans, again, contracted on the terminable principle are of various classes; the See also:chief of these are (1) See also:life annuities, (2) terminable annuities, (3) loans repayable by instalments at certain intervals, (4) loans repayable entirely at a fixed date. From the time of William III. life and terminable annuities have been a favourite mode in England either of borrowing money or of commuting, and thus gradually paying off, the existing funded debt. At first, and indeed until comparatively recent times, the system of life annuities resulted in serious loss to the country, owing to the calculation of the See also:rate of See also:annuity on too high a See also:scale, a result arising from imperfect data on which to See also:base estimates of the See also:average duration of life. The system of life annuities was sometimes combined in England with that of perpetual annuities, or interest on the permanent debt—the life annuity forming a sort of additional inducement to lenders of limited means to invest their money. At one time the See also:form of life annuities known as See also:tontine was much in See also:vogue both in England and France, the principle of the tontine being that the proceeds of the See also:total amount invested by the contributors should be divided among the survivors, the last survivor receiving the whole interest or annuity. The results of this system were not, however, encouraging to the state. In England, at least, the terminable annuity has been a favourite mode of borrowing from the time of William III.; it has been generally conjoined with a See also:low rate of permanent interest on the sum borrowed. Thus in 1700 the interest on the consolidated debt amounted to only £260,000, while the terminable annuities payable amounted to £308,407. In 178o a loan of 12 millions was raised at 4% at par, with the additional benefit of an annuity of £1, Os. 3d. % for eighty years. Even so See also:late as the See also:Crimean War in 1855, a loan of 16 millions at 3% at par was contracted, the contributors receiN See also:ing in, addition an annuity of 14s. 6d. % for See also:thirty years. The third method of contracting terminable loans, that of See also:gradual repayment or See also:amortization within a certain limit of years, has been 'a favourite one among certain nations, and specially commends itself to those whose credit is at a low ebb. When the final See also:term of repayment is fixed upon, a calculation is easily made as to how much is to be paid See also:half-yearly until the expiry of the term, so that at the end the whole, principal and interest, will have been paid. At first, of course, the amount paid will largely represent interest, but, as at each half-yearly See also:drawing of the See also:numbers of the bonds to be finally paid off the principal will be gradually reduced, there will be more and more money set See also:free from interest for the reduction of the actual debt. This method, as we have said, has its advantages, and when conjoined with stipulations as to liberty of See also:conversion to debt bearing a See also:lower rate of interest than that originally offered, and when the bonds are not issued at a figure much below par, might be the most satisfactory method of raising money for a state under certain emergencies. What is known as the " See also:Morgan loan " of France in 187o was contracted on such conditions. The last form of temporary loan, that repayable in bulk at a fixed date, is one which, when the sum is of considerable' amount, is See also:apt to be attended with serious disadvantages. The repayment may have to he made at a time when a state may not be in a position to meet it, and so to keep faith with its creditors may have to borrow at a higher rate in See also:order to pay their claims. It has, however, worked well in the See also:United States, most of the debt of which has been contracted on the principle of optional payment at the end of a short period, say five years, and compulsory payment at the end of a longer period, say twenty years. Thus the loan of 515 millions of dollars contracted in 1862 was issued on this principle, at 6 %, and so with other loans between that See also:year and 1868. In See also:European states, however, the risks of embarrassment are too great to permit of the application of this method on an extensive scale; and for loans of great amount the methods most likely to yield satisfactory results are loans bearing quasi-perpetual interest, or those repayable by instalments on the basis of half-yearly drawings within a certain period. What are known as lottery loans are greatly favoured on the continent, either as an See also:independent means of raising money, or as an See also:adjunct to any of the methods referred to above. These must not be confounded with the lottery pure and See also:simple, in which the contributors run the See also:risk of losing the whole of their investment. The lottery loan has been found to See also:work well for small sums, when the interest is but little below what it would have been in an ordinary loan, and when the percentage thus set aside to form prizes of varying amounts forms but a small fraction of the whole interest payable. The principle is that each contributor of such a loan has a greater or less See also:chance of drawing a See also:prize of varying amount, over and above the repayment of his capital with interest. What are known in England as See also:exchequer bills and treasury bills may be regarded as loans payable at a fixed period of short duration, from three months upwards, and bearing very in-significant interest, even so low as 1%. They are a useful means of raising money for immediate wants and for See also:local loans, and form handy investments for capitalists who are reserving their funds for a special purpose. Exchequer bonds are simply a special form of the funded debt, to be paid off generally within a certain period of years. There are two principal methods of issuing or effecting a loan. Either the state may See also:appeal dii ectly to capitalists and invite subscriptions, or it may delegate the negotiation to one or more bankers. The former method has been occasionally followed in France and See also:Russia, but in practice it has been found to be attended with so many disadvantages to the borrowing state or city that the best financial authorities consider it unsound. The great banking-houses have such a command over the money-market that it rsdifficult to keep even a direct loan out of their hands. The majority of loans, therefore, are negotiated by one or more of these houses, and the name of See also:Rothschild is See also:familiar to every one in connexion with such transactions. By this method a borrowing state can assure itself of having the proceeds of the loan with the least possible delay and with the minimum of trouble. A loan may be issued at, above, or below par, though generally it is either at or below par—" par " being the normal or theoretical price of a single See also:share in the loan, the sum which the borrowing government undertakes to pay back for each share on reimbursement, without See also:discount or See also:premium. Very generally, as an inducement to investors, a loan is offered at a greater or less discount, according to the credit of the borrowing government. Sometimes a state may offer a loan to the highest bidders; for example, the city of See also:Auckland in 1875 invited subscriptions through the See also:Bank of New See also:Zealand to a loan of £1oo,00o at 6%; offers were made of six times the amount, but only those were accepted which were at the rate of 98 % or above. The rate of interest offered generally depends on the credit of the state issuing the loan. England, for example, would have no difficulty in raising any amount at 3 % or even less, while less See also:stable states may have to pay 8 or 9 %. The nominal percentage is by no means, however, always an See also:index of the cost of a loan to a state, as the See also:history of the debt of England disastrously shows. During the 18th See also:century various expedients were employed, besides that of terminable annuities already referred to, to raise money for the great wars of the period, at an apparently low percentage. For example, from 3 to 5% would be offered for a loan, the actual amount of stock per cent. allotted being sometimes 1072 or even 11; so that between 1776 and 1785, for the £91,763,842 actually borrowed by the government, £115,267,993 was to be paid back. In 1797 a loan of £1,620,000 was contracted, for every £100 of which actually subscribed, at 3%, the sum of £219 was allotted to the lender. In 1793 a 3% loan of 4a millions was offered at the price of £72 %, the government thus making itself liable for £6,250,000. Greatly owing to this reckless method the debt of Great See also:Britain in 1815 amounted to over 900 millions. France in this respect has been quite as extravagant as England; many of her loans during the 19th century were issued at from 52i to 84%, one indeed (1848) so low as 45%—as a See also:rule with 5% interest. The enormous and embarrassing increase of the French debt during the 19th century was doubtless greatly due to this disastrous system. Nearly every European state and most of the Central and South See also:American states have at one time or another aggravated their debts by this method of borrowing, and got themselves into difficulty with their creditors. Financiers almost unanimously maintain that in the long run it is much better for a state to borrow at high interest at or near par, than at an apparently low interest much below par. A state of even the highest See also:rank may find itself in the midst of a crisis that will for a time shake its credit; but when the crisis is past and its credit revives it will be in a much more sound position with a high interest for a debt contracted at par than with a comparatively low interest on a debt much in excess of what it really received. If a state, for example, borrows at par at 6 % when its credit is low, it may easily when again in a flourishing condition reduce the interest on Its debt to 4 or even 3%. The United States government actually did so with the debt it had to See also:contract at the time of the See also:Civil War. This method of reducing the burden of a debt is evidently no injustice to the creditors of a government, when used in a legitimate way. A state is at liberty at any time to pay off its debts, and, if it can borrow at 3% to pay off a 6% debt, it may with perfect See also:justice offer its creditors the See also:option of payment of the principal or of holding it at a reduced interest. Government debts are, however, sometimes reduced after a See also:fashion by no means so legitimate as this. Other states have been even more unprincipled, and have got rid of their debts at one sweep by the simple method of repudiation. When a state has a variety of loans at varying rates of interest, it may consolidate them into a single debt at a See also:uniform interest. For example, in 1751 several descriptions of English debt were consolidated Into one fund bearing a uniform interest of 3 %, an operation which gave origin to the familiar term " See also:consols " (" consolidated annuities "). In the early days of the English national debt, a special tax or fund was appropriated to the payment of the interest on each particular loan. This was the See also:original meaning of " the funds," a term which has now come to signify the national debt generally. So also the origin of the term " funded." as applied to a debt which has been recognized as at least quasi-permanent, and for the payment of the interest on which See also:regular See also:provision is made. Unfunded or floating debt, on the other hand, means strictly loans for which no permanent provision requires to be made, which have been obtained for temporary purposes with the intention of paying them off within a brief period. Exchequer and treasury bills are included in this See also:category, and such other moneys in the hands of a government as it may be required to reimburse at any moment. Where a government is the recipient of savings See also:banks deposits, these may be included in its floating debt, and so also may the See also:paper-money which has been issued so largely by some governments. A state with an excessive floating debt must be regarded as in a very See also:critical financial condition. National debt, again, is divided into See also:external and See also:internal, according as the loans have been raised within or without the country— some states, generally the smaller ones, having a considerable amount of exclusively internal debt, though it is obvious that the bulk of national debts are both external and internal. We referred above to various ways of reducing the burden of a debt, and also to methods of contracting loans by which within a certain period they are amortized or extinguished. Most states, however, are burdened with enormous quasi-permanent debts, the reduction or extinction of which gives ample See also:scope for the financial skill of statesmen. A favourite method of accomplishing this is by the See also:establishment of what is known as a sinking fund, formed by the setting aside of a certain amount of national revenue for the reduction of the principal of the debt. (J. S. K.) The following table shows the general state of the See also:world's public indebtedness at the beginning of the loth century, divided according to the more important countries, the bracketed figures in See also:black type indicating the position of the country referred to under each heading in the See also:list. The figures are given by preference• for the year 1900, as more representative, in a case like this, than for some later years; for the See also:Boer War, as regards the United See also:Kingdom, and also the Russo-See also:Japanese War, introduced new debt and new considerations, hardly See also:fair to the comparison, while this stands at the and of a long period of See also:peace. The figures in every case are not to be supposed to be absolutely accurate; statistics of national debts differ, -often remarkably, and it is practically impossible to give a perfectly satisfactory compalison, owing partly to difficulties of computing the See also:exchange, partly to inaccurate accounts, and partly to the varieties of debt (reproductive or non-reproductive, &c.). Kingdom (756 millions) stood second to that of France (See also:i000 millions), in 1900 it' stood third to France and Russia; whereas in 1883 its See also:weight per See also:head of See also:population was third, in 'goo it was See also:eleventh; whereas in 1883 its See also:annual See also:charge stood second, in 1900 it stood See also:fourth; and whereas the weight of the charge per head of population in 1883 was fifth, in 1900 it was eleventh. The indebtedness of the great See also:British dependencies, on the other hand, had increased from 302 millions to 544 millions See also:sterling, or by 242 millions; and the local (municipal) debt of Great Britain had risen from about too millions to upwards of 300 millions. It is interesting to recall the history of the British national debt during the 19th century. The debt at the See also:close of the See also:Napoleonic war (1816) was nearly 887 millions sterling, and at the beginning of 1900 this debt had been reduced to 621 millions,' or a decrease of 266 millions—notwithstanding See also:interim additions of about 367 millions, which made the See also:gross reduction during that period 633 millions sterling, an amount actually larger than the whole (dead-weight2) debt at the end of the century. No country (except the United States, to a smaller amount) has ever redeemed its obligations on such a scale, and this was done while all other European countries of similar See also:standing were piling up debt. This enormous reduction was effected at different rates of See also:speed. Between 1817 and 1830, when what was known as History of Britisl' debt. The Principal Public Debts of the World, 'poo. Country. Population. Total Debt. Per Head. Annual Charge. Per Head. Additional information and CommentsThere are no comments yet for this article.
» Add information or comments to this article.
Please link directly to this article:
Highlight the code below, right click, and select "copy." Then paste it into your website, email, or other HTML. Site content, images, and layout Copyright © 2006 - Net Industries, worldwide. |
|
[back] NATIONAL ANTHEMS OR HYMNS |
[next] NATIONAL FLAGS |